The Dutch Fiscal Framework: Unique, or Transferable to Other Countries?

Posted by Frits Bos, CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis

Nl The Netherlands has a well developed and successful  medium term fiscal and budgetary framework that has helped stabilize government finances and has helped constrain the growth of the public sector. The Dutch framework is based on real expenditure ceilings and a sustainable deficit target over the medium term. Expenditure envelopes are fully planned in for the duration of government on the basis of a four-year “Coalition Agreement” between the political parties in government. Expenditure growth paths were based, until recently, on cautious assumption about the structural growth rate of the economy. To what extent is the Dutch framework, which has a number of specific institutional features, transferable to other countries? What are the strengths and weaknesses of the framework. Frits Bos, of the CPB (the Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis), discusses below the main features of the Dutch system. A recent paper published by Mr. Bos presents  the historical development, the procedures and the specific rules of the Dutch fiscal and budgetary framework

In the Netherlands, there is a long tradition of stressing rationality and efficiency in government budgeting. This goes back to at least the end of the nineteenth century, when the well-known Dutch economist Pierson became first Minister of Finance and later Prime Minister. Since then, many prime ministers and major politicians were economists. The important role of the CPB in economic and fiscal decision-making also reflects this dominance of economic thinking. 

The role of the CPB as adviser and arbitrator fits well in the Dutch tradition of consultation and coalition governments. Directly after the Second World War, the CPB played an important role in developing a joint strategy for economic recovery based on economic  analyses. Furthermore, the  qualities of CPB’s first director and  Nobel laureate. Jan Tinbergen,  contributed greatly to the appreciation of the CPB’s work. All these factors have helped support the development and acceptance of the rather sophisticated Dutch fiscal and budgetary framework.

Public debt and sustainability

The main  anchor of the framework is a fiscal balance target over the medium term, i.e. the term of government. There is no year-on-year targeting of the fiscal balance. Ideally the fiscal balance target should be aligned with long-term fiscal sustainability considerations . A decade ago, the CPB started to calculate generational accounts for the Netherlands. These calculations demonstrated that current budgetary arrangement (taxes, public expenditure on social security, education and health care,  subsidies, etc.) in the Netherlands were and are not sustainable. Under unchanged polices, the aging population will lead to a sharp and structural increase in public expenditure, in particular on state pensions and health care. Government revenue from taxes on funded pensions will also increase, but not enough to cover the extra expenditure and the falling revenues from natural gas. As a consequence, in the long run without policy adjustments public debt will explode and Dutch public finances will be out of control. Adjusting policy in time is efficient (tax smoothing limits the impact on the labor and capital markets) and is intergenerationally fair. At present the medium term fiscal balance target of the framework is some 2.5% of GDP removed from long-term sustainability.

Role of the CPB and the Advisory Group

One year before the elections, the road to a new coalition agreement and medium-term framework starts. The CPB makes provisional estimates of the Dutch economy and public finances in the medium term. These estimates are later updated and supplemented with an analysis of Dutch public finances in the long run.

All these estimates serve as inputs for the official advisory group on budgetary principles. The government makes explicit which topics should at least be addressed by the advisory group. In about half a year, this group writes a report evaluating past budgetary performance and making recommendations for the next period of government. The Ministry of Finance serves as the secretary of the advisory group. The CPB provides the estimates on the economy and public finances and is often asked to conduct analyses of the consequences of alternative assumptions and principles.
In the run-up to the general elections, the CPB publishes an analysis of the economic effects of the election programs of the political parties. The CPB conducts this analysis at the request of the political parties. The CPB study makes it possible to compare the parties’ election platforms on economic aspects. Key elements of the analysis are the implications for public finances, macroeconomic developments and purchasing power. 

After the elections, the CPB provides an analysis of the coalition agreement being developed by the winning political parties. The previous analysis of the election platforms is a great help in making such an analysis. When no entirely new policy measures are proposed compared to the election programs, a standard analysis (i.e. check on the plausibility and feasibility of the measures proposed and their ex-ante budgetary implications, macro-economic effects and effects for purchasing power) can be made within a few days.

The Ministry of Finance ultimately calculates the medium-term framework. For example,  the level of the real expenditure ceilings is fixed considering the coalition agreement and the most recent information about expenditure and revenue.  Other Ministries, in particular those on social affairs and health care, may also have a clear opinion on the development of the expenditure of their Ministry. Estimates by the CPB, in particular those on social security, taxes and health care, serve as a critical benchmark for fixing the medium-term framework.

This process for deciding on a new coalition-agreement implies that policy measures are checked in an early stage on their feasibility and consequences on the national economy and public finance in the medium term and long run.   

The CPB plays two important roles in the annual budgetary process. First, it provides the official macro-economic estimates, e.g. of economic growth, prices and wage rates, for the budget.  Secondly, it provides in depth estimates on Dutch public finances. As a consequence, there is always a critical counterpart for the estimates on Dutch public finance by the Ministry Finance. An essential feature of the CPB-estimates is that they can be based on the most recent budgetary information and decision-making, even when this information is not yet officially published. 

Elements of the framework

The major features of the current trend based fiscal and budgetary policy framework in the Netherlands are:

Unique or transferable to other countries?

In several respects, the Dutch fiscal and budgetary framework is unique in the world and reflects typical Dutch circumstances (e.g. a prevalence of coalition governments and the independent position of the CPB since World War II). Nevertheless, the Dutch fiscal procedures and specific rules could be relevant and transferable to other countries. Three examples can illustrate this:

A reason for the success of the Dutch framework are the various evaluation procedures that are in place. For good budgetary institutions, procedures and rules and a clear role in the political process, regular, official and good quality evaluation is crucial.  In the Netherlands, this role is played by the official advisory group on budgetary principles, the national court of audit, the interdepartmental evaluation groups and the CPB. For the CPB, also explicit checks have been introduced for ensuring relevance and scientific quality.

The Achilles' heel of the Dutch approach is the division of tasks between the official experts and the political process, and the need to respect each others prerogatives. Experts like the CPB should show economic consequences, alternatives, trade-offs and uncertainty, but refrain from becoming an active player in the political arena. A somewhat technocratic and dispassionate attitude of the expert (e.g. in terms of language and appearance in the media) is advisable. However, it should not imply that politically sensitive topics or solutions are evaded by the official expert. Politicians should leave room for official experts to voice their opinions, ensure their independence and the quality of their work.   

Recent